StudentShare
Contact Us
Sign In / Sign Up for FREE
Search
Go to advanced search...
Free

Effect of German Automobile Industry on Economy - Essay Example

Cite this document
Summary
This essay "Effect of German Automobile Industry on Economy" uses long-run real price and dividends series to investigate the German stock market. It tries to determine in what periods and to what degree the German stock market has also possessed “excess volatility”…
Download full paper File format: .doc, available for editing
GRAB THE BEST PAPER97.4% of users find it useful
Effect of German Automobile Industry on Economy
Read Text Preview

Extract of sample "Effect of German Automobile Industry on Economy"

The German Automobile Industry and the affect it has on the German Economy, Stock Utility Analysis This paper uses long-run real price and dividends series to investigate for the German stock market the questions asked of the U.S. market by Shiller (1989). It tries to determine in what periods and to what degree the German stock market has also possessed "excess volatility" in the past century in relation to the car industry. It finds no evidence of excess volatility in the pre-World War I German stock market indices in the car industry. By contrast, there is some evidence of excess volatility in the post-World War II German stock market. Introduction: The automobile industry plays a significant role in the German economy; every fifth job is directly or indirectly connected to it. This implies that Germany's economic strength is being impacted and influenced by the automobile industry to a great extent - making it one of the most dominating sectors. The value system in the German car industry can be broken down into four major players; component suppliers, car producers, dealers or the point of sale, and buyers. These players are all affected by any turbulence in the car industry. As a result they all contribute, to various extents, to the attempts of structural change taking place in the industry. As Muller and Reuss have argued perhaps what is most noticeable of the attempts at readjustments within the value system is the insecurity on the part of all players as to what the future direction of the industry will be. Background: Germany has a leading position in car manufacture worldwide, owing mainly to the fact that the focus was concentrated on high technology in order to be able to fulfill the increasing demands of the markets and to maintain the export power of German car manufacturers. The car industry, which represents a macroeconomic key industry for Germany, made a turnover of 202 billion EUR in 2001. 69% was attributable to manufacturers of motor vehicles and motors, a good 3% to the manufacturers of trailers, body work and containers; 28% to the car components and accessories industry. With this, the car industry made one-sixth of the total industrial turnover in Germany. With 121 billion EUR, the German car industry earned 60% of its sales in foreign countries. German car manufacturers and suppliers employ more than 1.5million people worldwide, more than half of them in Germany. Recently, domestic employment has been expanded; Since 1994, the number of jobs at home increased by122000.Despite economic weakness in 2002, employment in the car industry remained almost constant with 763 500 people. Owing to the assumption of additional value-added activities from the manufacturers, suppliers even employed additional staff. The German car industry employs more than 12.8% of the working population of the whole German industry. At the same time, it raises one third of the R&D expenditure of the German economy and one-fifth of the investments. During the last five years, 49 billion EUR were invested in Germany; over this period of time, expenditure for R&D exceeded 65 billion Euros, and the R&D staff was increased significantly to more than 70,000 employees (VDA, 2003). Literature Review: Germany was one of the European countries that succumbed early to the fascination of Fordist production methods. German automakers made pilgrimages in the 1920s to the USA, seeking to discover the secrets of the economic future at the holy cities of capitalism, which of course included the Ford plants at Highland Park and River Rogue. Creating the preconditions for a new age in automobile production was a strong motive behind numerous efforts to concentrate car production capacity in Germany. After the postwar stabilization of the economy, the large German banks - above all the Deutsche Bank - toyed with the idea of consolidating the most important German car producers into a large automobile trust, able to meet the challenge of Ford; Daimler, Benz, Opel and BMW were still only medium sized companies. Daimler and Benz merged in 1924-6. But all further efforts in this direction were hampered by unfavorable economic circumstances, and they ended abruptly in spring 1929 when Adam Opel AG was sold to General Motors at a large profit. This effectively ended serious discussion of a German Auto Trust and intensified what was known as the creeping crisis of the German automobile industry. This paper examines "excess volatility" in the market indices of major car manufacturers in the German stock market, investigating for that market the issues examined by Robert Shiller (1981, 1986, 1989) for the U.S. stock market. It finds some evidence that post-World War II German stock index prices in the car industry have been too volatile (relative to nave estimates of fundamentals) to have been rational forecasts of the present value of future dividends. Alternatively, pre-World War I stock prices were not volatile enough (relative to nave estimates of fundamentals). In either case, the efficient markets hypothesis appears inconsistent with observed behavior in one or the other of the periods. The focus of this paper is on the divergence of market outcomes in the two periods, and the difficulty of reconciling both patterns simultaneously with the efficient markets hypothesis. This paper examines the volatility of prices relative to dividends in order to avoid most of the biases in estimated volatility ratios generated by Shiller's (1981) original tests. Thus normalized, the pre-World War I German stock market shows not excess but deficient volatility: the market price dividend ratio is surprisingly far down in the lower tail of the distribution under the null hypothesis that prices are rational forecasts of fundamentals. Throughout the pre-World War I era, the market average dividend yield fluctuates in a narrow band between four and a half and five and a percent. By contrast, the post-World War II stock market (and especially the post-Wirtschaftswunder market) shows some evidence of "excess" volatility. The evidence of excess volatility in post- World War II German data is weaker than but of the same order of magnitude as the evidence using U.S. post-World War II data. The behavior of the pre-World War I German stock market thus is in sharp contrast to the behavior of the post-World War II German stock market, and to the behavior of the U.S. stock market in either the pre-World War I or the post-World War II period. We speculate that the dominance of the German Grobanken in the securities industry in the years before World War I may be the cause of the exceptional behavior of the pre-World War I German market. German Data: Donner (1934) compiles and reports a monthly nominal share price index-with attached estimates of average yearly dividend yields for the companies included in his aggregate index-for the German stock market from January 1870 to December 1913. His index covers only twelve companies from 1870 to 1875. The number of companies covered reaches twenty-one in 1876 and is nearly sixty by 1890. Majority of the companies included in the reports belongs to the automobile industry as such Volkswagen, Ford, BMW, Mercedes and Audi. Especially in the years from 1890 on, the Donner index is a sample of Germany's largest companies, weighted toward those heavy industries in which Germany's companies were largest and its international comparative advantage greatest. We begin our study in 1876, when the number of companies in the index rises above twenty. Donner's index ends with the beginning of World War I. An official index-unfortunately without dividends attached-covers the period from 1914 up to the 1923-24 hyperinflations (Statistisches Reichsamt, 1922a, 1922b). A second official index covering three hundred corporations extends from 1924 to the middle of World War II, reporting both the stock index price and a dividend yield (Statistisches Reichsamt, 1928, 1929). We splice the first official Statistisches Reichsamt (National Bureau of Statistics) series onto Donner's in 1914 to track the course of the German stock market up to the hyperinflation. We splice the second Reichsamt index onto the first to provide information about the course of the German stock market between the hyperinflation and the middle of World War II. For the post-World War II period, the stock price series we use links four official portfolio index series constructed by the post-World War II Statistisches Bundesamt (Federal Bureau of Statistics).We link from each series to the next in the first year in which the following sequence becomes available (see Herrman, 1956; Spellerberg and Schneider, 1967; Silberman, 1974; Ltzel and Jung, 1984; Statistisches Bundesamt, 1985). For the later interwar and the post-World War II periods, the yield series used is the yield on all traded stocks. Thus the yield is calculated from a different and larger sample of corporations than are the price indices. Nevertheless, the post-World War II dividend series-calculated by multiplying price and yield-is a good estimate of the dividend corresponding to the index. The nominal price and dividend series are deflated by the German consumer price index endorsed by the Deutsche Bundesbank (1976). This index runs continuously, with one gap covering World War II and the post- war reconstruction period Excess Volatility and the German Stock Market Shiller's (1981, 1989) first key insight was that the level of the stock market is a forecast of the ex post perfect-foresight fundamental. An investor who buys and holds, and pays less than the ex post fundamental, receives a supernormal return. Arbitrage, therefore, pushes prices in an efficient market to be efficient forecasts of the perfect-foresight fundamental. Shiller's second key insight was to apply the principal that efficient forecasts are less volatile than the ex post realized values of the quantities being forecast. If a forecast is more volatile, a better forecast could be constructed easily: shrink the original forecast toward its ex ante unconditional mean, and the resulting improved forecast will have a smaller mean squared error. These two insights imply that if the efficient markets hypothesis holds then stock prices should be less volatile-relative to their ex ante unconditional means, a notion that needs to be made precise-than the realized track of the ex post perfect-foresight fundamental. Biases in Testing for Excess Volatility As Flavin (1985), Scott (1985), Kleidon (1986a and 1986b), Mankiw, Romer, and Shapiro (1985, 1991), and many others have argued, Shiller's (1981) original comparison of the variance of deter ended prices and of deter ended ex post perfect-foresight fundamentals are subject to biases. Especially in small samples, such tests may well find apparent excess volatility even if in fact the efficient markets hypothesis holds. It is easiest to understand the source of these biases by examining the trading strategies associated with tests of excess volatility and return predictability. Each test of market rationality is implicitly associated with a portfolio strategy. If prices are too volatile relative to trend, investors at the time could have made better forecasts of ex post fundamentals-and earned high profits-by taking as their forecast some linear combination of the market price and a time trend, and betting that returns would be low whenever the market price was above the trend. If returns are predictable from a variable like the price-dividend ratio (Scott, 1985), investors could have earned supernormal profits by buying when the ratio was low and selling when it was high. If investors could in fact have followed the trading strategy implicit in the tests of market efficiency-and did not-then the rejection of market efficiency is genuine. But under some conditions the implicit trading strategy could not have been followed because it required more information for its execution than investors at the time possessed. In such a case, the rejection of market efficiency may well be spurious: investors may well have taken advantage of all profit opportunities open to them, and given the information at their disposal prices may have been the best available forecasts of the present value of fundamentals. For example, suppose log dividends follow a random walk with drift: Where g is the long-run upward rate of drift of dividends, and et is an innovation, un forecast able before period t. With a constant discount rate r, the efficient markets log real stock price will be: (2) pt = -ln(r-g) + dt Suppose an ex post time trend p is fitted to the first and last observations, t=0 and t=T: (3) pt= p0+Tt (pT- p0) Calculate the covariance between the one-year realized return r*t1: (4) r*t1= r + et and the price relative to the ex post time trend (conditional on knowledge of the current price pt and of the current value pt of the ex post trend): (5) E{r*t1 (pt-pt) | pt-pt} = - {Tt} E {et+12 | pt-pt} Equation (5) shows that there are excess returns from buying when the price is low relative to the ex post trend, and selling when it is high. Such a strategy earns excess returns off of the correlation between the deviation of the price from the ex post trend and future innovations. The return predictability in equation (5) comes solely from the use of the realized values of future shocks-shocks dated later than t-in constructing the value pt of the time trend, and in assessing whether prices are relatively low or high. Without this use of information about the realizations of future shocks, there are no excess returns to be earned: returns are uncorrelated with the deviation of the price from an ex ante time trend p't constructed by extrapolating drift from the series starting point. (6) p't= p0+ tg (7) E{r*t1 (pt-p't)| pt, p't} = 0 In this example, a regression of returns on prices and an ex post time trend is indeed likely to find significant return predictability and excess volatility. But such a finding is spurious: it arises from an implicit assumption that rational investors had more information about future shocks than they in fact possessed future shocks. Normalizing by the Level of Dividends To compensate for such biases, Mankiw, Romer, and Shapiro (1985 and 1991) proposed an alternative benchmark for the calculation of excess volatility. They argued that it is plausible that past investors knew nave forecasts of perfect-foresight fundamentals made by assuming them to be a constant dividend multiple. Tests of excess volatility relative to this alternative nave-forecast benchmark that takes fundamentals to be a constant multiple of dividends assume less in terms of investors' knowledge of the parameters and outcomes of the dividend process. This paper uses such a nave constant dividend multiple forecast as the benchmark against which to evaluate the efficient markets hypothesis. It normalizes real prices and ex post fundamentals by the current level of dividends. The pre-World War I stock market does not appear excessively volatile to the eye: the volatility of prices relative to the benchmark of twenty times dividends is smaller than the volatility of ex post fundamentals. The post-World War II market does see a larger volatility for prices relative to the twenty times dividends benchmark than for ex post fundamentals after 1960. The decade before1960 sees both prices and ex post fundamentals very far from normal multiples of dividends. Conclusion: This paper has used German data to investigate issues similar to those that Shiller (1989) has investigated in his studies of the United States stock market. The German data give different answers. There is some evidence of excess volatility in the post-World War II German stock market. But there is no sign at all of excess volatility in the pre-World War I German stock market. Relative to a nave forecast benchmark that takes fundamental values to be a constant multiple of dividends, the pre-World War I German stock market stands in contrast to both the post-World War II German market, and to the American market in either the pre-World War I or the post-World War II period. The substantive results of this paper suggest two additional lines of thought. The first is that in a sense the absence of excess volatility in the German stock market before World War I strengthens Shiller's conclusions for the United States. It is harder to maintain that Shiller's findings of violations of market efficiency are due primarily to biases in test procedures or to inappropriate assumptions about the stochastic character of generating processes when the pre-World War I German stock market- presumably subject to the same biases in test procedures -exhibits no signs of excess volatility. The U.S. stock market might have exhibited as low a degree of volatility relative to current dividends and perfect-foresight fundamentals as the pre-World War I German market. Yet it did not do so. This calls for explanation. The second additional line of thought is speculative. Perhaps the unusual behavior of the pre- World War I German market-in not showing evidence of excess volatility-is linked to the institutional structure of automobile industry under the German Empire Bibliography: Robert B. Barsky and J. Bradford De Long (1990), "Bull and Bear Markets in the Twentieth Century," Journal of Economic History 50 (June 1990), pp. 1-17. Robert B. Barsky and J. Bradford De Long (1989), "Why Have Stock Prices Fluctuated" (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University xerox). Rondo Cameron, ed. (1972), Banking and Economic Development (New York: Oxford UniversityPress). Rondo Cameron (1956a), "Founding the Bank of Darmstadt," Explorations in Entrepreneurial History Rondo Cameron (1956b), "The Credit Mobilier and the Economic Development of Europe," Journal of Political Economy 61 (December). John Campbell and Robert Shiller (1988), "Stock Prices, Earnings, and Expected Dividends," Journal of Finance 43 (July), pp. 661-76. Alfred Chandler (1990), Scale and Scope (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press). J.H. Clapham (1963), The Economic Development of France and Germany 1815-1914 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). John Cochrane (1991), "Volatility Tests and Efficient Markets: A Review Essay," Journal of Monetary Economics Alfred Cowles and Associates (1939), Common Stock Indices, 2nd ed. (Bloomington, IN: Principia Press). Barry Eichengreen (1992), Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression (New York: Oxford University Press). Alexander Gerschenkron (1952), "Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective," in BertHoselitz, ed., The Progress of Underdeveloped Areas (Chicago: University of Chicago Press). Charles P. Kindleberger (1973), The World in Depression (Berkeley, CA: University of CaliforniaPress). Allan Kleidon (1986a), "Variance Bounds Tests and Stock Price Valuation Models," Journal of Political Economy 94 (October), pp. 953-1001. David S. Landes (1969), The Unbound Prometheus (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). Stephen LeRoy (1989), "Efficient Capital Markets and Martingales," Journal of Economic Literature 28, pp. 1583-1621. Stephen LeRoy and Richard Porter (1981), "The Present Value Relation: Tests Based on Implied Variance Bounds," Econometrica 49 (May), pp. 555-74. N. Gregory Mankiw, David H. Romer, and Matthew D. Shapiro (1991), "Stock Market Forecast ability and Volatility: A Statistical Appraisal," Review of Economic Studies 58:3 (May), pp. 455-77. N. Gregory Mankiw, David Romer, and Matthew D. Shapiro (1985), "An Unbiased Reexamination of Stock Market Volatility," Journal of Finance 40 (July), pp. 677-87. N. Gregory Mankiw and Matthew D. Shapiro (1986), "Do We Reject too Often Small Sample Bias in Tests of Rational Expectations Models," Economics Letters 20, pp. 139-45. Robert Merton (1987), "On the Current State of the Stock Market Rationality Hypothesis," in Ruddier Dornbusch, Stanley Fischer, and John Bossons, eds., Macroeconomics and Finance: Essays in Honor of Franco Modigliani (Cambridge, MA: M.I.T. Press). James M. Poterba and Lawrence H. Summers (1988), "Mean Reversion in Stock Prices: Evidence and Implications," Journal of Financial Economics 22, pp. 1-26. Louis Scott (1985), "The Present Value Model of Stock Prices," Review of Economics and Statistics 67, pp. 599-604. Robert Shiller (1989), Market Volatility (Cambridge, MA: M.I.T. Press). Robert Shiller (1986), "Comments on Miller and on Kleidon," in Robin Hogarth and Melvin Reder, eds., Rational Choice: The Contrast between Psychology and Economics (Chicago: University of Chicago Press). Robert Shiller (1981), "Do Stock Prices Move too Much to Be Justified by Subsequent Changes in Dividends" American Economic Review 71 (June), pp. 421-36. Gustav Stolper (1940), The German Economy 1870-1940 (New York: Reynal and Hitchcock). Peter Temin (1989), Lessons from the Great Depression (Cambridge, MA: M.I.T. Press). Kenneth West (1988), "Dividend Innovations and Stock Price Volatility," Econometrica 56, pp. 37-61. Read More
Cite this document
  • APA
  • MLA
  • CHICAGO
(“The German Automobile Industry and the affect it has on the German Essay - 1”, n.d.)
The German Automobile Industry and the affect it has on the German Essay - 1. Retrieved from https://studentshare.org/miscellaneous/1505114-the-german-automobile-industry-and-the-affect-it-has-on-the-german-economy-stock-utility-analysis
(The German Automobile Industry and the Affect It Has on the German Essay - 1)
The German Automobile Industry and the Affect It Has on the German Essay - 1. https://studentshare.org/miscellaneous/1505114-the-german-automobile-industry-and-the-affect-it-has-on-the-german-economy-stock-utility-analysis.
“The German Automobile Industry and the Affect It Has on the German Essay - 1”, n.d. https://studentshare.org/miscellaneous/1505114-the-german-automobile-industry-and-the-affect-it-has-on-the-german-economy-stock-utility-analysis.
  • Cited: 0 times

CHECK THESE SAMPLES OF Effect of German Automobile Industry on Economy

Managing Business in Europe: Automotive Industry in European Union

The increasingly international setting of business makes it harder and harder to establish the boundaries of a national economy or even to separate the European economy from its global context (Wallace &Young, 1997, p.... This paper analyses the influence of EU's policies on Automotive industry, the influence of Single European Market or EMU on Automotive industry, opportunities and threats for Automotive industry associated with the enlargement of the EU, and automotive industry strategies for Europe, etc....
12 Pages (3000 words) Term Paper

United States Automobile Industry

United States automobile industry ... , the total impact of the automobile industry goes far beyond the direct impact.... he US automobile industry is highly concentrated, with domestic production dominated by a tight triopoly.... Auto Industry and US EconomicsThe automobile industry has long been viewed... he auto industry is one of the most influential segments in the US economy, providing a substantial fraction of the national employment and having a major impact on GDP....
14 Pages (3500 words) Essay

The German Automobile Industry

This essay "The german automobile industry " discusses industry-level collective-wage agreements that have been replaced by various variable-pay systems, such as group-based bonus systems or performance-based compensation.... nlike the free market f the United States, in which companies are less likely to contribute to the development f industry-wide training systems due to the risk f losing skilled workers to competing firms and the possibility f collective action problems in developing public training programs, the German corporatist institutions f trade unions and employer associations implemented highly developed vocational training by limiting the free-riding in the process f training....
18 Pages (4500 words) Essay

Economic Profile of Automobile Industry

The paper contains an economic profile of the automobile industry which is one of the most important industries in the world, generating billions of dollars in world revenues, placing more than 806 million vehicles on the roads, accelerating the business activities and linking person to person.... The automobile industry with its gas-guzzling pollutant spewing vehicles has been a source of interest for everyone; the owners, drivers, pedestrians and also the breathers of air polluted by automobiles....
9 Pages (2250 words) Case Study

Economy Affection on the Automobile Industry

The paper "Economy Affection on the automobile industry" discusses that the automotive industry in America is currently facing a big challenge for survival.... (DeMarines) The growth of the automobile industry was huge before the current economic recession starts.... automakers were short on accepting blame themselves, and long on blaming high gas prices, the credit crisis and a global recession for the sales downturn and their economic dire straits' (Henry)When we analyze all the above factors we can conclude that the automotive industry is directly linked with the economy of a country....
7 Pages (1750 words) Case Study

The US Automotive Industry

According to the study conducted by the Motor & Equipment Manufacturers Association and Information Handling Services, the overall automobile industry's direct employment generation was 3.... automobile industry, its history, and development, and finds that it is the backbone of the manufacturing industry, therefore, plays a vital role in strengthening the American economy.... The paper "The US Automotive industry" portrays the US as the home to 13 automobile manufacturers, one of the major automotive markets....
7 Pages (1750 words) Research Paper

Germanys Economic Performance during the Credit Crunch

An intense focus emerged in Europe when Greece announced that its economy was in the verge of collapse.... This led to one standing economy, Germany, contributing to its bailout.... Throughout this case study, I will highlight german's economic indicators from the period of the financial crisis to date and also talk about monetary policies that may have put Germany in a strong position during the credit crunch.... german ultimately became the major supplier of bailout funds to ailing European economies....
8 Pages (2000 words) Assignment

The United States Automobile Industry

The paper "The United States automobile industry" investigates Historical development of the automobile industry, economic dynamics of industry development in the USA, the traits of The Business Cycle in Auto Industry, supply, demand, and supply curve for a number of car manufacturers, etc.... Considering all the intermediate products used in auto construction and distribution, the total impact of the automobile industry goes far beyond the direct impact....
10 Pages (2500 words) Term Paper
sponsored ads
We use cookies to create the best experience for you. Keep on browsing if you are OK with that, or find out how to manage cookies.
Contact Us