StudentShare
Contact Us
Sign In / Sign Up for FREE
Search
Go to advanced search...
Free

How Poverty Has Been Measured Internationally - Research Proposal Example

Cite this document
Summary
The paper "How Poverty Has Been Measured Internationally " states that generally, the technique was illustrated by probing into the trend in complete and relative poverty in the UK, employing figures from two years of the “Family expenditure survey”. …
Download full paper File format: .doc, available for editing
GRAB THE BEST PAPER98.8% of users find it useful
How Poverty Has Been Measured Internationally
Read Text Preview

Extract of sample "How Poverty Has Been Measured Internationally"

Running Head: DISCUSS HOW POVERTY HAS BEEN MEASURED INTERNATIONALLY Discuss How Poverty Has Been Measured Internationally [Name of Institution] Discuss How Poverty Has Been Measured Internationally Poverty is an importunate dilemma that has offered political and ethical challenges to all societies around the globe at all times. If analyzed, the word poverty, itself, is a familiar one that everyone comprehends, or considers they understand. But the particular meaning we connect to the word depends upon the original notion of poverty we have in mind. It is feasible to visualize poverty in many different traditions, each one guiding towards a different perception of the meaning and importance of the term, towards a different exact definition, which in turn will direct to equivalent differences in the methods and events used to approximate the numbers in poverty and determine the depth of their hardship. If we analyze, we come to know that there is much debate pertaining to how one measures and calculates poverty. To arrive at a conclusion or gist of poverty, a series of hard measurement choices must be made. For example: is poverty a virtual or absolute conception What is the desirable poverty line What is the suitable unit of scrutiny: the household, the relations or the individual What is the finest alternate measure of well-being What equality balance should be used Another difficulty, which has established less awareness in the experimental study of poverty, is the blow of compositional aspects on the measurement of poverty. More particularly, the degree of poverty, however defined, is pretentious by the demographic evaluation of the population for which it is worked out. (Gordon, et. al, 2000) For the intentions of comparing transforms and amendments in poverty over time (or across areas or between groups), it would be supportive to be capable to determine differences in poverty as if there would have been no modifications in compositional factors. This dilemma of compositional factors in the measurement of poverty is simply illustrated by orientation to the most fundamental review measure of poverty - the "head-count ratio" - that is merely the percentage of persons (or homes or families) in a population which is deprived. After dividing a populace into "k = 1, 2K" mutually restricted and thorough subgroups, the head-count ratio at two varied points in time, "t" and "t-1", for this population may be articulated as: From these uncomplicated identities, it is easy to observe that the dissimilarity in the head-count ratio (i.e. %Poort - %Poort-1), will be estimated by both distinctions in the head-count ratios of each of the subgroups (i.e. %Poorkt - %Poorkt-1) and by differences in the qualified population shares of each of the subgroups (i.e. skt - skt-1). In thorough analyses of poverty, researchers are principally concerned with differences in poverty after the outcome of differences in population creation has been eradicated. Cumulative or summary poverty measures, such as the head-count ratio, regrettably bewildered these two effects, often making it difficult to understand observed differences in the occurrence and strength of poverty (Gordon, 2003). This paper formulates a method for scheming for compositional factors in the measurement of poverty. The method is dependable with Sen's (1986) prominent axiomatic paradigm to poverty measurement and employs the accepted poverty index projected by Foster et al. (1984). This index is one of the many synopsis poverty measures that can be unswervingly standardized and also assembles Sen's criteria. The technique is illustrated by examining the tendency in unconditional and relative poverty in the UK. Statistics from the "Family expenditure survey", covering the phase 1968 to 1986, are used. The specific experiential focus is the relationship between household composition and poverty. Fisher (2002) elaborated three characteristics that a good summary index of poverty must contain. It must be perceptive to: the comparative number of poor, capturing the occurrence of poverty; the standard level of earnings of the poor, pointing their average deficiency and the allotment of earnings among the poor, pointing their intensity of relative deprivation. A poverty measure that holds these characteristics, and meets Sen's norms, is the index projected by Foster et al. (1984) (regarded to as the FGT measure). This measure, P(), may be illustrated (with the household as the element of surveillance) as: here y* is line of poverty; yi is the earning of domestic i; q is the number of unfortunate households in the populace (i.e. with yi < y*); and n is the total number of households in the populace. "" is a variable, which takes on a rate greater than or identical to zero ( 0). As gets bigger, the measure becomes more responsive to the income conditions of the "poorest poor". (Pichaud, 1988) At its plainest poverty refers to a fundamental be short of the means of continued existence; the poor are those who, even in typical state of affairs, are incapable to nourish and clothe themselves appropriately and risk death as a result. This account would probably draw worldwide acknowledgment and assent. Moreover such a situation would possibly be seen as one, which should if possible be rectified, although specifically how this should be done may be a matter of disagreement. It is the case that there are some regions in the world where tremendous poverty of this kind is rampant and affects large numbers of people; in these cases it may be hard in practice to argue persuasively for a less severe concept and definition of poverty. An appraisal of empirical studies proposes that the concept of poverty as absolute deficiency continues to be of primary significance in countries where per capita income is low and the occurrence of poverty is high. In this way, this definition has become more and more unacceptable in those parts of the world where higher universal levels of living have been achieved. In countries experiencing rapid development and obvious reductions in the incidence of absolute deficiency, poverty is gradually more defined in relative terms. As the threat of hunger recedes, questions relating to the suitable distribution of income and opportunity presume greater importance. In these circumstances the definition of poverty moves away from a negligible, physical survival view in the course of a relative, anecdotal definition which puts increasing stress on social endurance and starts to attach cost to the quality of life that even the poorest in a population should be able to enjoy. A different glossary is developed to introduce ideas of social contribution, of inclusion and segregation, of citizenship, of empowerment. The design of relative poverty is a powerful one, but it is also contentious, and hence the poverty question is everywhere an ardently contested one, involving grim issues of social, political and moral significance (Townsend, 2000). In those societies where poverty is perceived to be a problem that requires remedial action of some kind, these arguments are further complex. Is remedial action the liability of charitable individuals, and if so who, what and how Is it a broader family or communal responsibility Should the state or the government be implicated and if so why and how All of these are matters upon which people will feel permitted to have a view and therefore to differ with one another. Thus the first component in the analysis of poverty is to deal with the issue of the material level that distinguishes the poor (those in poverty) from others. Sometimes the conversation stops overall at this point. The problem of poverty (being poor) is accessible as no more than a question of material property, usually uttered in terms of cash. This is unquestionably a necessary section, especially in those societies where most transactions are facilitated by transfers of cash for preferred goods or services. But money for what Any effort to establish a poverty line articulated as a minimum cash prerequisite must be based upon some unambiguous or implicit assumptions about what that money is desired for; some intellect of what wants must be addressed if the individual is not to undergo intolerable deprivation, what goods or services it is sensible for everyone, even the poorest, to enjoy. That this argument is also contested reminds us that the elementary issue is not the money itself-which has no inherent worth-but the effect that the lack of money has on the lives and lifestyles of the poor. In the same way, a cash-deficiency definition of poverty serves as no more than a makeshift pointer, and to focus upon it wholly may be to overlook other magnitude of poverty that cannot be simply condensed to monetary values. According to Townsend (2000) the common emphasis upon cash-poverty is omitted and myopic. The conception of poverty needs to be a much fuller and more wide-ranging one, concerned with much more than what money can buy. It has a moral dimension, which, if overlooked, sternly impoverishes, even distorts, any poverty debate. Fundamentally, what is nasty about poverty, and why it matters so much, is that poor people are incapable to sustain a degree of manage over their own lives by the exercise of choice. For most people daily life is an invariable succession of decisions and choices, from the most insignificant to the most important. These choices help to fashion the excellence of a person's life and that of the family to which they belong. Most choices, however, have source implications. They engage decisions about how to use the limited resources at one's disposal. For poor people, with few possessions, the area of effectual choice is constricted, and one measure of the intensity of poverty is the thinness of residual choice. Razafindrakoto (2003) considers that this concept of poverty is universally justifiable, although it must be interpreted thoughtfully. A global understanding of poverty must recognize that there are major cultural differences, patterns of custom and conference, of social anticipation, which help to conclude in any particular case the parameters within which choice is exercised, and the priorities, which individuals will react to. But it is also the case that as the scope of marketization will vary between societies at diverse stages of social and economic expansion, so a narrow distress with cash-poverty alone without additional reference to genuine social and cultural situations, in all their intricacy, is to appoint in a discussion without real meaning. Definitions of poverty will replicate the causal notion that has been accepted, and just as poverty can be conceptualized along a gamut from the most supreme to the most relative, so there is an array of definitions (Gordon, 2003). The most crucial definition will spotlight on the capacity to survive. In its narrowest sense this may denote nothing more than having the funds to purchase or grow adequate food for oneself and one's dependants. The only needs that are recognized are biological ones, food, water, and in intimidating climates, clothing and safe haven. No allowances are made for broader social requirements, and no acknowledgment is given to social or cultural outlook. Using such a definition guarantees that any gauge of the numbers in poverty will acquiesce the smallest possible form. Recommendations for policy interventions would thus be restricted in capacity and character, and the force evaluation standards would be meek. Definitions based on an absolute concept of poverty permit its measured pervasiveness to change over time. They need an absolute poverty line based on endurance criteria, such as a particular minimum daily caloric intake (Bradshaw, 2000) the quantity of income spent on food or the income level mandatory to purchase some minimum basket of utilization goods. The once familiar use of caloric intakes alone to conclude poverty lines is in decline. It has been argued (for example, by Streeten, 2000) that the daily caloric intake is an defective measure of poverty. Except in extraordinary circumstances such as natural disasters and famines, poor people infrequently die of starvation. This is partly because daily energy requirements diverge with the kind and sum of activity being undertaken. Principally, however, it is because low calorie intake has effects that are neither immediate nor necessarily measurable, for example increased susceptibility to disease. An apt minimum level of daily energy necessity is therefore difficult to institute. Numerous international agencies have sought to manufacture a constant poverty line that permits certain comparisons to be made. As we see that the latest World Bank research on poverty for example uses US$1 per day (converted to local currency to reproduce local prices) as a minimum poverty line (Fisher, 2002). The data produced using this computation is based on survey data from the countries concerned. Thus the US$1 per day line is pretty subjective. It has been adopted to facilitate comparison, to allow measurement at diverse places and various times, thus allowing comparisons to be made, and mindsets affirmed. So far, it has been established that poverty is the most severe social problem in front of the international community. As we have seen, even though the specific content of poverty definitions will differ between countries, the indispensable nature of poverty as a situation is worldwide. Poverty is about exclusion. It is a wide-ranging and multifaceted phenomenon, overpoweringly affecting individuals and households. The stress on exclusion directs us to the heart of poverty: that the lack of resources prevents participation in the regular life of the community. The fastidious form of those resources will be different in different communities, as will the thinking of what constitutes a normal lifestyle. The primary concept is straightforward, but operationalizing it is multifarious, and profoundly political. Our concept of poverty establishes our definition, and our definition determines our measures. What we decide to measure, and how, gives us the problem we choose to confront, and thus shapes our policy. We have seen that the apparently academic questions of poverty-definition and measurement-have thoughtful consequences for policy and practice, and thus for those now condemned to poverty and its penalty. Unless and until the poverty problem is effectively conceptualized, defined and measured, immeasurable millions will continue to endure. In conclusion the acquired method is based on the demographic technique of straight standardization and shift-share investigation. With this method, it is likely to examine the core trend in poverty while scheming for compositional factors branded to be correlated with the occurrence and strength of poverty. The technique was illustrated by probing into the trend in complete and relative poverty in the UK, employing figures from two years of the "Family expenditure survey". In this interlude, there has been a discernible change in the allocation of households by type. Based on our postulations, there has been a cut in absolute poverty and an enhancement in relative poverty. This verdict is reliable and supplementing other studies that have examined the trend in poverty in this period (Christina, 2006). However, the scale of the turn down in absolute poverty and the amplification in relative poverty is reliant on the particular poverty index used - and not unpredictably on the stage at which the poverty line is position. A comparison of inconsistent and consistent poverty ratios implies that the collapse to control for shifting household configuration in the sequential measurement of poverty leads to underrate of the fundamental decrease in absolute poverty and overvalue of the underlying augment in comparative poverty. This means that the decline in absolute poverty is "bigger" and the boost in relative poverty is "minor" (less optimistic) when the amendment is measured through standardized rates contrasted to unstandardized rates. The decomposition research interprets that the pragmatic changes in the largely poverty rates are clarified chiefly by changes in the poverty rates of diverse types of family circle and not by changes in allocation of households by kind. Nevertheless, the relative significance of the "poverty effect" and the "composition effect" relies on both the detailed poverty index used and the rate of the poverty line preferred. References Bradshaw, J. (2000), "Poverty and Social Exclusion in Britain", York: Joseph Rowntree Foundation. Christina, P. and Nandy, S. (2006), "Poverty and Social Exclusion in Britain: The Millennium Survey", Policy Press, Bristol Fisher, G. M. (2002), "The Development and History of the Poverty Thresholds", Social Security Bulletin, Vol. 55, pp.3-14. Foster, J., Greer, J., Thorbecke, E. (1984), "A class of decomposable poverty measures", Econometrica, Vol. 52 pp.761-66. Gordon, D. (2003) Child Poverty in the Developing World, Bristol, The Policy Press. Gordon, D., Adelman, L., Ashworth, K., Bradshaw, J., Levitas, R., Middleton, S., Pantazis, C., Patsios, D., Payne, S., Townsend, P. and Williams, J. (2000) Poverty and Social Exclusion in Britain, York: Joseph Rowntree Foundation. Pichaud, D. (1988), "Poverty in Britain 1899 to 1993", Journal of Social Policy, Vol. 17 pp. 335-49. Razafindrakoto, M. (2003), "New International Poverty Reduction Strategies", New York, pp. 15-17. Sen, A.K. (1986), "Poor, relatively speaking", Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 35 pp.153-69. Streeten, P. (2000), "Beyond the Six Veils: Conceptualizing and Measuring Poverty". Journal of International Affairs, Vol. 52 No. 1, pp.1-4. Townsend, P. (2000), "Breadline Europe: The Measurement of Poverty", The Policy Press, Bristol. Read More
Tags
Cite this document
  • APA
  • MLA
  • CHICAGO
(“Social policy and development Research Proposal”, n.d.)
Retrieved de https://studentshare.org/sociology/1534086-social-policy-and-development
(Social Policy and Development Research Proposal)
https://studentshare.org/sociology/1534086-social-policy-and-development.
“Social Policy and Development Research Proposal”, n.d. https://studentshare.org/sociology/1534086-social-policy-and-development.
  • Cited: 0 times

CHECK THESE SAMPLES OF How Poverty Has Been Measured Internationally

Law To Eliminate Poverty

Further, this number has been soaring if one takes into account the last year analysis according to which around 900,000 people are badly suffered at the hands of the recession (Pasma, 2010).... The writer of the paper "Law To Eliminate poverty" states, that law is an effective instrument to control the issue of poverty but it also requires other factors to participate towards the annihilation of poverty such as the government of a country and people residing in any country....
13 Pages (3250 words) Essay

Domestic Poverty in the United States

One of such scholars are Danziger & Haveman (2001), who studies and tried to understand various parameters of domestic poverty in the United States as well as how it has been growing since the times of the World War II.... One of the major advantages of this kind of research method that has made me to choose it in my research is that it is inexpensive to undertake since it does not require data collection procedures.... Another factor that has played a very great part in causing domestic poverty is the increasing gap between the rich people and the poor people....
11 Pages (2750 words) Research Paper

UK Poverty and the Policy Surrounding It

"UK Poverty and the Policy Surrounding It" paper analyzes the progress that has been commenced by the government and citizens of the country to fight poverty.... The British administration has taken a step to eliminate poverty in the country such as child poverty and social exclusion.... Moral underclass discourse is majorly focused and emphasizes on the moral and cultural causes of poverty, and puts much concern on the dependency of some in the state benefits....
17 Pages (4250 words) Essay

Poverty in India

million which since 1990-2005 has been growing at 1.... ndia was basically an agriculture based economy, in the year 2005, agriculture's proportion to GDP has been declining as the economy is progressing and agriculture was 18.... India is the third largest economy in the world according to the measures of purchasing power parity with a GDP of 1 trillion USD as measured in 20071.... But, the author still argues that with all the changes or step towards improvement is not quite visible in the masses of the country; that is the effect is not quite trickled down to the lower economic classes and only the top 20% have been benefiting from it....
11 Pages (2750 words) Research Paper

Auses, Effects and Finest Ways to Measure Poverty Issues

Although, poverty is normally measured as to be unwanted due to the pain and misery it might cause.... here are several factors that have been mentioned to explain why poverty takes place.... Altogether 270 million people, the majority of them women and children, have been expired as a result of poverty ever since 1990's.... However, no single reason has gained universal recognition.... poverty is deficiency of those objects that establish the quality of life which includes clothing, food, clean drinking water and shelter....
5 Pages (1250 words) Essay

Poverty and Underdevelopment in Modern Times

A country is said to be underdeveloped if it has a high rate of illiteracy.... According to the study, poverty and Underdevelopment in Modern Times, the more underdeveloped countries are those that are yet to develop.... These three are not only indicators of poverty, but are also indicators of underdevelopment.... Simply put, poverty is the outcome of a country's underdevelopment.... poverty is an issue that cannot be easily alleviated....
8 Pages (2000 words) Essay

A Measure of Freedom

Can freedom be measured?... Can freedom be measured?... If we are to view freedom from an economic perspective, then freedom can most assuredly be measured statistically.... However, the operational definition of what legitimately constitutes freedom, in a fashion that would satisfy the majority, has yet to be developed which makes freedom measurement difficult to justify using existing criteria in various quantitative or qualitative measurement instruments....
7 Pages (1750 words) Essay

Poverty Line Measurement Analysis

he World Development Report released in 2001 wherein poverty was measured based on 1 dollar-a-day poverty lined revealed that: 1) of all the world's 6 billion people – 2.... The study "poverty Line Measurement Analysis" seeks to determine whether the 'one dollar-a-day' poverty line is a reasonable indicator of poverty across the world.... The result found emphasized the lack of capability by measures based on it because fundamentally, they do not answer social, cultural and other country-specific variables that characterize poverty....
8 Pages (2000 words) Case Study
sponsored ads
We use cookies to create the best experience for you. Keep on browsing if you are OK with that, or find out how to manage cookies.
Contact Us